fbpx

Publications

Pharmaceuticals: Life-Saving Benefits That Pay for Themselves

Economic Note explaining the underestimated benefits of pharmaceutical innovation, and the key role that pricing plays in encouraging it

Ottawa has the prices of drugs in its sights. On the one hand, it has made changes to the calculation method for the price ceilings imposed on drugs sold in Canada. On the other, the idea of national government pharmacare to replace the provinces’ mixed plans is still in the air. These ill-advised public policies could actually raise total health care spending, while threatening Canadians’ access to the best available treatments, shows this publication by the MEI.

Related Content

To save money and lives, make drug approval easier (National Post, February 5, 2020) Interview with Peter St. Onge (Afternoons with Rob Breakenridge, Newstalk 770 CHQR, February 5, 2020) Interview with Peter St. Onge (Bloomberg Markets, BNN, February 5, 2020)

Interview with Peter Germain Belzile (CTV News Montreal at Noon, CFCF-TV, February 17, 2020)

 

This Economic Note was prepared by Peter St. Onge, Senior Economist at the MEI, with the collaboration of Germain Belzile, Senior Fellow at the MEI. The MEI’s Health Policy Series aims to examine the extent to which freedom of choice and entrepreneurship lead to improvements in the quality and efficiency of health care services for all patients.

The federal government currently has the prices of drugs in its sights. It has made changes to the calculation method used by the Patented Medicine Prices Review Board (PMPRB) in order to lower the price ceilings imposed on prescription drugs.(1)

The same rationale also partly explains politicians’ proposals to impose government-run pharmaceutical insurance from coast to coast, replacing the provinces’ mixed plans.(2) These ill-advised public policies are based on a misunderstanding of the market for drugs, their underestimated benefits, and the key role that pricing plays in encouraging the arrival of new treatments.

Pharmaceutical Innovation Pays for Itself

Focusing exclusively on costs obscures the substantial savings we reap from pharmaceutical innovation, as drugs often replace even more expensive medical treatments—a phenomenon known as “offset effects.”

The contribution of pharmaceutical innovation to health and well-being in the modern world is substantial. Between 1995 and 2012, life expectancy at birth in Canada rose by 3.6 years, from 78.0 to 81.6, while hospital use, measured in discharges per capita, decreased by 25%, largely thanks to new drugs.(3) A study of 30 countries covering the period 2000-2009 found that pharmaceutical innovation is responsible for fully 73% of the increase in life expectancy during this period, or a gain of 1.27 years in just a decade.(4)

These benefits are much cheaper than other interventions such as surgery, with a cost per life-year gained thanks to pharmaceutical innovation of as low as US$2,730.(5) This compares with an average of US$61,000 or more per year of dialysis, a cost benchmark across medicine.(6)

There is a growing literature on these offset effects. One US study estimated that if a 15-year-old drug is replaced by a 5.5-year-old drug, non-pharmaceutical spending falls by US$72 per capita on average, four times greater than the US$18 per capita the new drug actually costs.(7) Thus greater drug spending actually reduces total health spending compared to what it would have been given other reasons like the aging of the population. However, the price of the drug is more visible, and becomes an easy target for bureaucrats or politicians.

This offset effect is present across medicines and across conditions, ranging from twice the cost of the drugs in hospital care alone, up to eight times the cost of the drugs once all health system offsets are accounted for.(8) Additional benefits accrue from fewer seniors in nursing homes, fewer workers forced to rely on disability insurance, and other savings.(9)

Further research has documented these offset effects. One Canadian study found new drugs save an average of 4.7 times their cost in reduced medical expenditures.(10) Even in the US, where drugs are significantly more expensive, a government study estimated that a 1% increase in the number of annual prescriptions actually translates into a 0.2% decrease in annual heath care costs, working out to US$94 saved per prescription.(11)

One study covering seven OECD countries found that offset effect savings actually increase with time, so that each new drug provides US$5.90 in net benefits for every person in the United States, with those benefits doubling to US$11.40 in the long run.(12)

Beyond reducing costs, offset effects can also help compensate for doctor shortages. One Dutch study concluded that ten new drugs introduced from 1995 to 2007 to treat three categories of diseases saved so much in reduced health care use alone that they were equivalent to hiring 720 full-time health care professionals for each new drug introduced.(13)

The consistent pattern is that pharmaceutical innovation, in addition to its health benefits in lives saved and quality of life improvements, more than pays for itself in savings elsewhere, both in terms of health care and outside benefits.

This puts rising pharmaceutical costs in an entirely different light, suggesting we should use more, not less, drugs to replace other treatments. In particular, we should be looking to eliminate all obstacles to increasing pharmaceutical R&D in order to benefit as much as possible from these offset effects. ​

The High Cost of Research

Despite their substantial benefits, the rising use of drugs has led politicians to think of them as a drain on public funds and to target the industry that produces them for its allegedly unconscionable profits.(14) In reality, the industry itself is not as profitable as many imagine.

Total net income—profit per dollar of revenue—for the US pharmaceutical industry is, at 15%, higher than the average across all US industries, but remains lower than margins in similarly high-risk industries such as general real estate (16%) and videogames (16.6%).(15)

One reason for this more modest level of profitability is the high cost of research and development. The R&D-to-sales ratio is 18.7% for the pharmaceutical industry in the US, compared to an average R&D ratio of just 2.9% among all US industries.(16)

This six-fold ratio is driven by enormous and increasing R&D costs per drug—themselves largely the result of ill-advised government policies. According to a 2016 study, the cost of bringing a new drug to market has risen to nearly US$3 billion. The process takes 15 years on average, with another US$300 million in post-approval R&D. Over the past 20 years these costs have soared at an average rate of 8.5% per year, faster than drug prices, and far faster than the economy at large.(17)

Pharmaceutical R&D has become so expensive in part because many drugs tested never make it to market. The same 2016 study found that of all drugs that enter clinical testing, 40% fail Phase I, 64% of the remaining drugs fail Phase II, 38% of those survivors fail Phase III, and another 10% fail to make it through regulatory review to final approval. The overall probability of clinical success through all these steps comes out to just under 12% (see Figure 1).(18)

If seven out of eight drugs don’t make it to market, of course, those seven failures must be paid for by the profits of the single drug that does make it. This creates an obvious target as alleged price-gouging, but the fact of the matter is that many drugs are highly valuable for patients, and payers are willing to pay for them.

The Threat to Tomorrow’s R&D

In countries with substantial government intervention in the drug market, politicians have methodically forced prices down below total costs. This leaves one country, the United States, footing the bill for the rest.

To illustrate, the prices Canada mandates for pharmaceuticals would, if applied in the US, not only end R&D, but actually bankrupt the industry. Pharmaceutical R&D is particularly sensitive to lower prices. One recent study estimates a $100 drop in revenue is associated with a $58 drop in R&D spending.(19)

Given that R&D makes up 18.7% of pharmaceutical revenue, such a relationship suggests that pushing prices down just 16% could halve pharmaceutical R&D, while a one-third reduction in prices could, conceivably, wipe out pharmaceutical R&D. Of course, the industry would respond dynamically along the way to such a decrease, walking away from the most ambitious new products and focusing on the cheapest or least innovative drugs.

At present, Canadian prices for patented medicines are actually 70% lower than US prices. This gap has worsened dramatically, dropping from 57 cents on the dollar in 2008 to 30 cents just nine years later.(20) Recent changes to the PMPRB will artificially reduce drug prices in Canada even further.(21)

Europe is no better. In the UK, for example, they pay 28 cents on the dollar compared to Americans. In Germany and Switzerland, they only manage 33 cents, and just 22 cents in France (see Figure 2).(22)

By tempting Americans to copy its seeming “free lunch,” Canada risks undermining the one market that actually sustains pharmaceutical R&D as we know it.

Let the Pharmaceutical Market Work

Pharmaceutical innovation has improved our lives tremendously, curing diseases and helping us manage symptoms in ways that would have astounded our ancestors. It has accomplished this progress, moreover, while generating savings elsewhere in the health care system that more than offset the cost.

But the need for innovative drugs, and for better versions of existing drugs, has not disappeared. Heart disease, cancer, diabetes, and many other conditions still rob people of years of life and health even in the richest countries. Meanwhile, research and development is risky and expensive, leaving access to new and better drugs vulnerable to government interference.

What would move Canada most toward sustainable pharmaceutical pricing would be to simply let private insurers negotiate market rates with drug manufacturers, allowing them to weigh the trade-offs of prices vs. benefits of new drugs while competing for subscribers. Then Canada could set its own reference prices as some average of those private insurers’ rates to ensure they are getting a fair price. The prices paid for drugs would then tend to represent sufficient profits for insurers to continue to make new drugs available to Canadians in a timely fashion, which would encourage research and benefit us and our children in the future.

As for reducing drug prices, a better way to do so would be to scale back the overregulation that needlessly inflates costs for drug manufacturers. With lower costs, sustainable R&D could occur at prices perhaps dramatically lower even than today. At the very least, the government should refrain from making things worse by nationalizing drug insurance and further constraining Canadian prices from reflecting the reality of this market that is so important to everyone’s well-being.

References

  1. Mathieu Bédard, “Reducing Drug Prices Too Much Will Make Them Inaccessible,” Viewpoint, MEI, April 18, 2019; Kelsey Rolfe, “Pharma companies launching challenge to PMPRB changes,” Benefits Canada, August 27, 2019.
  2. Michel Kelly-Gagnon, “Reasons to resist a national pharmacare monopoly,” National Post, October 8, 2019.
  3. Frank R. Lichtenberg, The Benefits of Pharmaceutical Innovation: Health, Longevity, and Savings, Research Paper, MEI, June 15, 2016, pp. 5 and 9-10.
  4. Frank R. Lichtenberg, “Pharmaceutical Innovation and Longevity Growth in 30 Developing and High-Income Countries, 2000-2009,” Health Policy and Technology, Vol. 3, No. 1, March 2014, pp. 36-58.
  5. Frank R. Lichtenberg, op. cit., endnote 3, p. 5.
  6. Chris P. Lee, Glenn M. Chertow, and Stefanos A. Zenios, “An Empiric Estimate of the Value of Life: Updating the Renal Dialysis Cost-Effectiveness Standard,” Value in Health, Vol. 12, No. 1, 2009; Steven Ross Johnson, “Home dialysis grows despite cost and logistical hurdles,” Modern Healthcare, October 11, 2014; W. Kip Viscusi, “The Value of Risks to Life and Health,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 31, No. 4, December 1993.
  7. Frank R. Lichtenberg, “Are the Benefits of Newer Drugs Worth Their Cost? Evidence from the 1996 MEPS,” Health Affairs, Vol. 20, No. 5, September 2001, pp. 241-251.
  8. Idem.
  9. Frank R. Lichtenberg, op. cit., endnote 3, pp. 14-15 and 17.
  10. The median savings ratio is 1.5, suggesting that some drugs generate very large savings, while others are relatively modest. Pierre-Yves Crémieux, Pierre Ouellette, and Patrick Petit, “Do Drugs Reduce Utilisation of Other Healthcare Resources?” Pharmaco Economics, Vol. 25, No. 3, March 2007.
  11. Darius Lakdawalla et al., “What Do Pharmaceuticals Really Cost in the Long Run?” American Journal of Managed Care, Vol. 23, No. 8, August 2017.
  12. Rexford Santerre, “National and International Tests of the New Drug Cost Offset Theory,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 77, No. 4, 2011, pp. 1033-1043.
  13. Apostolos Tsiachristas et al., Medical innovations and labor savings in health care: An exploratory study, Maastricht University, January 2009.
  14. Peter Loftus, “Drugmakers, Worried about Losing Pricing Power, Are Lobbying Hard,” The Wall Street Journal, September 24, 2019.
  15. Aswath Damodaran, Margins by Sector (US), Stern School of Business at New York University, 2016 to 2020.
  16. Idem.
  17. Joseph A. DiMasi, Henry G. Grabowski, and Ronald W. Hansen, “Innovation in the pharmaceutical industry: New estimates of R&D costs,” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 47, May 2016. The 2013 dollars were adjusted to 2019 dollars using the Bureau of Labour Statistics CPI Inflation Calculator. There is an active debate over the methods used in this widely-cited estimation; for example see James Love, “The 2016 Tufts estimates of the risk adjusted out-of-pocket costs to develop a new drug,” Knowledge Ecology International, April 12, 2016.
  18. Idem.
  19. Carmelo Giaccotto, Rexford E. Santerre, and John A. Vernon, “Drug Prices and Research and Development Investment Behavior in the Pharmaceutical Industry,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 48, No. 1, April 2005, pp. 195-214, cited in Frank R. Lichtenberg, op. cit., endnote 3, p. 26.
  20. Patented Medicine Prices Review Board, Annual Report 2017, Figure 20, p. 41.
  21. Kelsey Rolfe, op. cit., endnote 1.
  22. Patented Medicine Prices Review Board, op. cit., endnote 20.
Back to top