fbpx

Publications

Would a $15 Minimum Wage Accelerate the Rural Exodus?

A strike of fast food restaurant employees in New York in 2012 gave birth to a movement demanding a substantial increase of the minimum wage in the United States, calling for it to rise to $15 an hour. Since then, several cities and states have established timelines for raising the minimum wage to that symbolic threshold. In Quebec, the major labour unions have taken up the charge, along with the symbolic $15 target. Many analysts who have commented on this debate have pointed out that a large number of jobs would be threatened if the hourly minimum wage rose rapidly from its current level of $10.75 to $15.

Media release: $15 minimum wage: The 25 RCMs where jobs are most at risk

Technical Annex
 

Related Content

L’IRIS et la politique de l’épouvantail (The MEI's Journal de Montréal blog, December 8, 2016)

Salaire minimum à 15 $: la «bombe atomique» ciblerait les régions (Le Soleil, December 11, 2016)

Interview (in French) with Alexandre Moreau (Que la Mauricie se lève, FM 106,9, December 8, 2016)

Interview (in French) with Alexandre Moreau (Solide comme le Roch, FM 104,7, December 8, 2016)

Interview (in French) with Mathieu Bédard (Maurais Live, CHOI-FM, December 9, 2016)

Debate (in French) with Alexandre Moreau (Au coeur du monde, Radio-Canada, 9 décembre 2016)

Interview (in French) with Alexandre Moreau (Mario Dumont, LCN-TV, December 8, 2016)

Interview (in French) with Mathieu Bédard (Les infos, V-Télé, December 12, 2016)

Interview with Mathieu Bédard (CTV News at Noon, CFCF-TV, December 20, 2016)

Would a $15 Minimum Wage Accelerate the Rural Exodus?

A strike of fast food restaurant employees in New York in 2012 gave birth to a movement demanding a substantial increase of the minimum wage in the United States, calling for it to rise to $15 an hour.(1) Since then, several cities and states have established timelines for raising the minimum wage to that symbolic threshold, including New York, San Francisco, Seattle, Los Angeles, and Washington, D.C., as well as the province of Alberta.(2) In Quebec, the major labour unions have taken up the charge, along with the symbolic $15 target.(3)

Many analysts who have commented on this debate have pointed out that a large number of jobs would be threatened if the hourly minimum wage rose rapidly from its current level of $10.75 to $15. Indeed, an employee’s work creates additional value for an employer, but if that value is less than the employee’s salary, it is not in the company’s interest to employ him or her.

Jobs are therefore destroyed when the minimum wage increases too much. Some economists estimate that 160,000 jobs would be lost in Quebec in the long term if this change were to take place in 2016, or 80,000 if it were to take place in 2022, whereas others think instead that 20,000 jobs would have been lost in 2015.(4)

Whether we adopt one estimate or another, the effect of this policy on the province’s rural regions can shine a light on the extent of its negative impact. Indeed, the jobs at risk represent a disproportionate share of rural employment, and such a measure could very well accelerate the rural exodus.

Different Effects from One Region to Another

The minimum wage, which is determined by the Quebec government for the entire province, does not affect all regions the same way. This is due to the fact that the volume of economic activity is not the same across Quebec.

These developmental differences affect the job market. Rural areas in particular are often places where productivity is low.(5) This is not due to workers and the quality of their work, but to economic conditions in the region. As a result, wages are generally lower in rural areas than in big urban centres.

The wage levels that businesses are able to offer are largely due to the region in which they are located. Generally, business opportunities are more numerous for companies located near big urban centres, and the wages offered there are higher. Despite this difference between big urban centres and rural regions, the minimum wage is applied uniformly across the province, thus having particularly negative effects on employment in rural regions.

Although these effects are always present when there is a minimum wage, some analysts estimate that they are small at the current level of $10.75.(6) However, if the minimum wage were set at a much higher level, like $15 an hour, these effects could quickly become much more apparent.

The portion of the labour force currently earning wages below the $15 threshold would be placed at risk by such an increase.(7) For these at-risk jobs, several economic adjustments are possible. Some employees would indeed keep their jobs and see their wages rise to $15 an hour. However, their workload could increase or include greater responsibilities. Others would lose their jobs, have their hours cut back, and/or receive fewer non-monetary benefits like the training, rebates on uniforms, or free meals that certain employers offer.(8)

The difference between the volume of economic activity in the big urban centres of Quebec and the province’s rural regions suggests that at-risk workers in regional county municipalities (RCMs) in and around large cities will be affected by less painful kinds of adjustments, whereas workers in rural regions will be affected by more difficult adjustments like job losses.

Moreover, in big urban centres, minimum wage increases mainly affect the young, often students working part-time, whereas in rural regions these increases especially affect low-income adults. Although certain analysts downplay the gravity of job losses for the young,(9) job losses for workers who may have families to support are far more serious. In rural regions, these would be the main victims.

Figure 1 presents the percentage of the labour market that would be placed at risk by such a minimum wage increase in the 25 most-affected RCMs if it were implemented in 2017.(10) Given that wages increase naturally year after year, the more this measure is delayed, the more its negative effects are reduced. But even if the increase were to happen in 2021, the at-risk population would still be sizable. In the Rocher-Percé RCM, for example, 56% of the labour force between 25 and 64 years of age would be at risk if this increase were implemented in 2017, versus 46% in 2021.(11)

The share of the labour market that would be at risk because of such an increase is much smaller in the RCMs surrounding the big urban centres of Montreal, Quebec, and Ottawa–Gatineau.

Numerous Adverse Effects

Studies of the minimum wage issue have already identified several adverse effects of setting the minimum wage at an unrealistically high level:

– It reduces employment among the young and among unqualified workers, since the labour of such workers often creates low added value.(12)

– Since it increases unemployment, it encourages participation in certain criminal activities, especially among the young.(13)

– Since businesses often have to raise their prices in order to be able to increase wages, it makes the prices of consumer goods go up in such a way as to disadvantage the low-income workers it is supposed to help.(14)

– Since in periods of recession the revenues of businesses fall, but the minimum wage remains fixed, it aggravates economic crises for workers at the bottom of the salary range.(15)

– Finally, it encourages young people to drop out of school by making entry-level salaries on the market more attractive, for those who manage to find a job.(16)

As we have just seen, it would also have the effect of discouraging rural economic development, thus accelerating the rural exodus which certain regions of Quebec have been struggling with since the middle of the 20th century.

There are other policy tools, some of which already exist in Quebec, that do not have these negative effects and can achieve the same objective of helping low-income workers. There is, for instance, the option of raising the basic personal amount on which no one pays income tax, or increasing and expanding the eligibility conditions for the solidarity tax credit or the work premium. These measures have much fewer negative side effects.

While bolstering these programs would entail a certain financial sacrifice on the part of the government, at least it would avoid negatively affecting businesses and a substantial portion of the workers we want to help. Resorting to these tools would also have the benefit of not creating a veritable “atomic bomb” striking the most economically vulnerable regions of Quebec, to borrow economist Pierre Fortin’s expression.

This Economic Note was prepared by Mathieu Bédard, Economist at the MEI, and Alexandre Moreau, Public Policy Analyst at the MEI. The MEI’s Regulation Series seeks to examine the often unintended consequences for individuals and businesses of various laws and rules, in contrast with their stated goals.

References

1. Steven Greenhouse, “How the $15 Minimum Wage Went From Laughable to Viable,” The New York Times, April 1, 2016.
2. Amrita Khalid, “Here are the cities and states that will soon have a $15 minimum wage,” The Daily Dot, August 14, 2016; Dean Bennett, “Alberta makes $15 minimum wage regulations official,” Toronto Star, September 13, 2016.
3. See the website http://minimum15.quebec/.
4. Marc Van Audenrode and Pierre Fortin, “Un débat qui favorise le populisme ambiant,” Le Devoir, November 8, 2016; Mathieu Dufour, Raphaël Langevin, and Dany Caron-St-Pierre, Quels seraient les effets réels d’une hausse marquée du salaire minimum? Institut de recherche et d’informations socioéconomiques, October 27, 2016.
5. George J. Stigler, “The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 59, No. 3, June 1951, pp. 185-193; Allyn A. Young, “Increasing Returns and Economic Progress,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 38, No. 152, December 1928, pp. 527-542; Jeffrey J. Yankow, “Why Do Cities Pay More? An Empirical Examination of Some Competing Theories of the Urban Wage Premium,” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 60, No. 2, September 2006, pp. 139-161.
6. Marc Van Audenrode, for example, argues that the youth unemployment rate can be a good indirect indicator and that it is relatively low in Quebec compared to abroad. See Martine Turenne, “Le salaire minimum à 15$, peu probable à court terme,” Le Journal de Montréal, August 30, 2016.
7. In fact, certain jobs paying much more than $15 an hour would also see adjustments, for example less generous wage increases or reductions in benefits, following modifications at the bottom of the salary range. It is not as straightforward, however, to calculate the effect on workers above the minimum wage threshold.
8. Anne Royalty, Do Minimum Wage Increases Lower the Probability that Low-Skilled Workers Will Receive Fringe Benefits? Indiana University-Purdue University Indianapolis and Stanford University, August 2000.
9. Mathieu Dufour, Raphaël Langevin, and Dany Caron-St-Pierre, op. cit., endnote 4, pp. 36-37.
10. For further details on our methodology, see the Technical Annex accompanying this Economic Note on the MEI’s website.
11. To see the effect of the increase in 2021 on the other RCMs, see the Technical Annex on the MEI’s website. The year 2021 was chosen because it corresponds to the year when the minimum wage will reach $15 an hour in several large American cities. It is also the year used to make projections by Gérald Fillion, “Le Québec aura son salaire minimum à 15 $ l’heure en 2021 ou en 2037?” Radio-Canada, April 18, 2016, whereas 2022 is used by Marc Van Audenrode and Pierre Fortin, op. cit., endnote 4.
12. Jonathan Meer and Jeremy West, “Effects of the Minimum Wage on Employment Dynamics,” The Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 51, No. 2, 2016, pp. 500-522; David Powell, Synthetic Control Estimation Beyond Case Studies: Does the Minimum Wage Reduce Employment? Rand Working Paper, No. WR-1142, February 2016; Shanshan Liu, Thomas J. Hyclak, and Krishna Regmi, “Impact of the Minimum Wage on Youth Labor Markets,” Labour, Vol. 30, No. 1, March 2016, pp. 18-37.
13. Masanori Hashimoto, “The Minimum Wage Law and Youth Crimes: Time-Series Evidence,” The Journal of Law & Economics, Vol. 30, No. 2, October 1987, pp. 443-464.
14. Thomas MaCurdy, “How Effective Is the Minimum Wage at Supporting the Poor?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 123, No. 2, April 2015, pp. 497-545; Sara Lemos, “The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Prices,” Institute for the Study of Labor, Discussion Paper, No. 1072, March 2004.
15. Jeffrey Clemens, “The Minimum Wage and the Great Recession: Evidence from the Current Population Survey,” NBER Working Paper, No. 21830, December 2015.
16. Laura Giuliano, “Minimum Wage Effects on Employment, Substitution, and the Teenage Labor Supply: Evidence from Personnel Data,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 31, No. 1, January 2013, pp. 155-194.​

Back to top